Dear Matthew Dale,I guess I can't request titles written in pinyin.
A request you have placed:
Title: Hayeke he ta de si xiang
Author: Yin Haiguang
TN: 2842
has been cancelled by the interlibrary loan staff for the following reason:
Could not verify
We couldn't find the correct item with the information you provided.
Tuesday, November 30, 2010
Automated Interlibrary Loan Notification, 30th Nov., 2010.
Monday, November 29, 2010
Public Attitudes in Hong Kong Towards Laissez-Faire, 29th Nov., 2010.
"Public Attitude toward Laissez Faire in Hong Kong," a fascinating but overlooked 1990 paper by Lau Siu-kai and Kuan Hsin-chi (Asian Survey 30(8): 766-81, available on Jstor with subscription) shows this is just wishful thinking. Admittedly, the public in Hong Kong strongly supports the label of laissez-faire (literally translated as "noninterventionist economic policy"). When asked how they felt about the laissez-faire policy of the Hong Kong government, 1.8% strongly disagreed, 22% disagreed, 54% agreed, and 3.5% strongly agreed. I doubt you'd see numbers like that in the U.S.But it turns out that Hong Kong's support for laissez-faire is only skin-deep. As soon as you ask people their opinions about specific interventionist policies - all of which, note the authors, "have either not been performed by the government or performed only very light or rarely," they show their true statist colors.
Sunday, November 28, 2010
Hayek and Early Hong Kong Policy, 28th Nov., 2010.
F. A. Hayek was discussing and writing about free markets at this time, but “it was Cowperthwaite who provided the textbook example showing economically liberal policies leading to swift economic development. His practical example provided confidence to the Thatcher and Reagan governments, and was a key influence in China’s post-Mao economic liberalization.” Since the index on economic freedom in the world began in 1970, Hong Kong has ranked number one every year, and “No one deserves more credit for this lofty rating than Sir John Cowperthwaite.”
Milton Friedman called Sir John Cowpathwaite serving as Finance Secretary an “accident of officialdom.” He mentioned the paradox that when “Britain was embarking on an extreme socialist policy in the homeland, one of its last remaining colonies, Hong Kong, was embarking on an extreme free-market policy.” (Gwartney 2006, pp. v)
Saturday, November 27, 2010
Hayek in Hong Kong's Universities, 27th Nov., 2010.
Friday, November 26, 2010
Government Structures in China, 26th Nov., 2010.
When making changes, there is the uncertainty between choosing slow, gradual reforms, or so-called “shock therapy.” Observers looked at the immediate chaos of Eastern Europe after the fall of the Soviet Union, and have drawn their conclusions from that short period, still today. However, “many Eastern European countries' standards of living are already very close to those in Western Europe,” and “the people of those countries, no matter in public policy or the commoners, all believe reform is a thing of the past, a sentence ending with a period.” By contrast, the Chinese government is still debating “how the next Chinese economic reform should advance,” making the process “. . . a sentence ending in a question mark, still continuing.” (Chen 2009)
Thursday, November 25, 2010
Theories on Economic Policy Reforms, 25th Nov., 2010.
A system based on centralized authority “has usually been found to be negatively associated with innovativeness.” This stems from the generalization that leaders at the top “are poorly positioned to indentify operational-level problems, or to suggest relevant innovations to meet these needs.” However, once a decision has been formulated, centralization “may encourage the implementation of innovations, once the innovation-decision is made.” (Rogers 1995, pp. 379-380)
Wednesday, November 24, 2010
Hayek's Literary Work, 24th Nov., 2010.
Tuesday, November 23, 2010
Private Markets in North Korea, 23rd Nov., 2010.
As of May 26, the government no longer forces markets to close at 6 or 7 p.m., has dropped the rule restricting customers to women older than 40 and has lifted a ban on certain goods being sold. An official in the city of Pyungsung informed the Good Friends humanitarian group that the living standard had "drastically decreased since the currency exchange, and the government cannot provide distribution so they have to bring the market back up."
The Good Friends newsletter quoted the official as saying: "There are increasing deaths from starvation so opening [the] market is a reasonable resolution. Death due to starvation has gone out of control."
In the mid-1990s, amid a total collapse of the central planned economy, somewhere between 3 and 5 percent of the population -- perhaps 1 million people -- died of starvation. Meanwhile, North Koreans increasingly turned to small markets for trading and buying supplies.
Monday, November 22, 2010
Hayek in Hong Kong, 22nd Nov., 2010.
They are doing really wonderful things in Hong Kong. If you want to know more, their policy journal, Best Practice, is a fantastic read.
Sunday, November 21, 2010
S. C. Tsiang's Influences Through the Decades, 21st Nov., 2010.
The basis of that book was the belief that
"The middle way, which--for reasons which will I hope become clear--I have called the Liberal-Socialist Solution, must proceed by making full use of the money and pricing systems, but so controlling those systems that three fundamental conditions are fulfilled: first, that the total monetary demand for goods and services is neither too great nor too small in relation to the total supply of goods and services that can be made available for purchase; secondly, that there is a tolerably equitable distribution of money income and property so that no individual can command more than his fair share of community's resources; and thirdly, that no private person or body of persons should be allowed to remain uncontrolled in a sufficiently powerful position to rig the market for his own selfish ends." (pp. 11)In the 1950s, S. C. Tsiang began to question the foundations of these principles. It wasn't until reading the literature of F. A. Hayek and Ludwig von Mises in the Socialist Calculation Debate did he completely reject socialism. I hope to finish the article later.
Saturday, November 20, 2010
China, the Great Utopia, 20th Nov., 2010.
"That democratic socialism, the great utopia of the last few generations, is not only unachievable, but that to strive for it produces something so utterly different that few of those who now wish it would be prepared to accept the consequences, many will not believe until the connection has been laid bare in all its aspects." (pp. 36)
Friday, November 19, 2010
Hayek on the Development of the Rule of Law in China, 19th Nov., 2010.
"I cannot speak with any competence about the interesting fact that the one great non-European civilization, that of China, appears to have developed, about the same time as the Greeks, legal conceptions surprisingly similar to those of Western civilization." (pp. 456)
Thursday, November 18, 2010
Mises in China, 18th Nov., 2010.
He believes Mainlanders are more eager for free markets and libertarianism, and points to the fact that many of the theory's leading books have only been published in jianti (simplified) characters. Ayn Rand's Atlas Shrugged was published in Chongqing before Taiwan.
Wednesday, November 17, 2010
Eureka! 17th Nov., 2010.
"Full of poison,'' is how a Chinese introduction described his 1944 book 'Road to Serfdom,' which was made available to high-ranking communist cadre to acquaint them with the 'enemy's' thinking, according to William McGurn in the 2000 book 'China's Future: Constructive Partner or Emerging Threat?'
Tuesday, November 16, 2010
Hayek and the New Youth Movement, 16th Nov., 2010.
Monday, November 15, 2010
Class Schedule, 15th Nov., 2010.
BUS 459-01 Business Policy and Strategy for B.S. MajorsBUS 457-01 Strategic Issues in Global BusinessBUS 240-01 Business LawBUS 499-01 Hayek in China
Sunday, November 14, 2010
Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve, 14th Nov., 2010.
Saturday, November 13, 2010
Friday, November 12, 2010
Types of Reform, 12th Nov., 2010.
"Lastly, in regards to the route taken during Russian and Eastern European privatization, there have been a lot of misunderstandings. As for the results of the so-called "Shock therapy," I think too many academics still make their conclusions from the conditions in the mid- to late-90s. There hasn't been anyone today that has gone back to Eastern Europe and looked around, seen the difference between today's Eastern Europe and the Eastern Europe of the 90s. Recently I was discussing gradual reform versus shock therapy with an Eastern European academic. He said that in Eastern Europe this is not an issue, because reform there has already finished completely. Not only that, but many Eastern European countries' standards of living are already very close to those in Western Europe. For example, the countries that were split up, such as Czechoslovakia, Yugoslavia, and the Soviet Union, the people of those countries, no matter in public policy or the commoners, all believe reform is a thing of the past, a sentence ending with a period. By contrast, how the next Chinese economic reform should advance is still a sentence ending in a question mark, still continuing. Therefore, to say "Eastern European reform has been a failure, but Chinese gradual reform is a success," does not stand on its own. One has already finished, but the other is still underway. What is China's next step?"
Thursday, November 11, 2010
Receptiveness, 11th Nov., 2010.
Wednesday, November 10, 2010
Downward Diffusion, 10th Nov., 2010.
"China is a country with a long-standing tradition of the centralization of state power. In this kind of country, any systemic innovation must gain high level approval. China's rural-level democracy developed under the support of high level leaders. High level leaders, especially the hard work and dedication of [Chairman] Peng [of the Standing Committee of the National People's Congress], are the key element to the initiation of basic Chinese democratic development. (The construction of the Chinese market economy also started like this.)"
Tuesday, November 9, 2010
Land Reform in Taiwan, 9th Nov., 2010.
"On the one hand, the KMT monopolized political power at the national level, suppressed dissent, controlled the mass media, and preempted social organizations that might constitute bases for opposition. On the other hand, the party-state paid utmost attention to improving the material well-being of the population and considered economic performance the ultimate source of legitimacy for the regime." (Page 142.)"The party-state monopolized political power because presumably it knew what was best for the country and needed concentrated authority in order to overcome obstacles when implementing its policies. Economic reform thus advanced much faster than political reform. People were asked to accept the enlightened rule of the technocrats, backed by the supreme leader, because by so doing they could expect economic prosperity in return." (Page 144.)"Reform began in agriculture, through different approaches were used in the two cases. In Taiwan, a land reform eliminated the traditional landlord class and redistributed lad to the tillers. On the mainland, the state decollectivized agriculture and allotted land among peasant households. The results were similar. Both reforms created a large number of peasant proprietors farming smallholdings. The production motive was maximized as income power was transferred to individual producers. As it turned out, the land reform laid the foundation for Taiwan's rapid economic development over the following four decades, and the restoration of family farming intitiated the whole reform process on the mainland in the 1980's." (Page 147.)
Monday, November 8, 2010
Chinese Literature on Hayek, 8th Nov., 2010.
Professor Zhenglai Deng, of Fudan University (Shanghai), seems to have the most work published. The publishing houses are interesting; Peking University Press, Jiangxi People's Press, Shandong People's Press, Hebei University Press, Fudan University Press, Intellectual Property Press, etc.
Sunday, November 7, 2010
Innovation in the Market and under Central Planning, 7th Nov., 2010
Two reasons came to my mind. The first is deteriorating conditions, such as lower standards of living or outright starvation. The second is comparison between living conditions between economies, or in other words: keeping up with the Joneses.
This may explain the background behind the People’s Republic of China and other Chinese societies that have chosen more market-oriented economies, such as Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan.However, this correlation would not be as strong in a closed, authoritarian country. This theory does not hold up when compared to North and South Korea. (All data from Maddison, 2003.)
I borrowed Comparative Economic Transformations: Mainland China, Hungary, the Soviet Union, and Taiwan by Yu-shan Wu from the Armacost Library. The key question he/she (?) asks is “What causes an authoritarian regime that fully controls a society to restructure its economy?” (Page 2.) The three principles of Roman Law are considered in defining property rights, the foundation of an economy. (Page 4.)
- usus (the right to use the thing)
- fructus (the right to the proceeds of a thing)
- abusus (the right to dispose of a thing)
Usually, command economies have transitioned to either market socialism or state capitalism.
“[T]hree historical cases stand out as offering the greatest potential for making comparisons with the PRC in the area of restructuring industrial property rights: Hungary in the late 1960’s and the 1970’s, the Soviet Union in the late 1920’s, and the Republic of China (ROC) in Taiwan in the 1950’s and early 1960’s. [ . . . ] Each had experienced a major liberal institutional change in agriculture before making the critical decision to reform is property rights structure. In Hungary, it was a marketizing reform in agriculture that followed the completion of the recollectization drive of the 1960’s. In the Soviet Union, it was the shift from requisitioning under War Communism (voennyi kommunizm) to a single tax in kind under the New Economic Policy. In Taiwan, it was the “land-to-the-tiller” reform of the 1950’s. In the PRC, similar changes were made in agriculture under the household responsibility system. The causes of these agricultural reforms are similar: the desperate desire of the elite to boost regime legitimacy by radically changing property rights structures in order to motivate peasants to increase food production in the aftermath of a major national disaster. The suppression of the 1956 popular uprising and the recollectivization campaign in Hungary, the catastrophic civil war and War Communism in the Soviet Union, and the effects of land reform in mainland China and the squashing of a serious local rebellion in Taiwan forced the ruling elite in each country to take drastic measures to assure that the most basic needs of the population were met. This was also the case in the PRC, which introduced agricultural reform in the aftermath of the disastrous Cultural Revolution decade.” (Page 12-13.)This brings me to the next book that I am consulting: Diffusion of Innovations by Everett M. Rogers. In it, diffusion is defined as “the process by which an innovation is communicated through certain channels over time among the members of a social system.” (Page 5.) The four main elements in the diffusion of innovations are “the innovation, communication channels, time, and the social system.”
Discussing centralization, Rogers writes,
“Centralization is the degree of which power and control in a system are concentrated in the hands of relatively few individuals. Centralization has usually been found to be negatively associated with innovativeness; that is, the more that power is concentrated in an organization, the less innovative the organization tends to be. The range of new ideas in an organization is restricted when a few strong leaders dominate the system. In a centralized organization, top leaders are poorly positioned to indentify operational-level problems, or to suggest relevant innovations to meet these needs. Although the initiation of innovations in a centralized organization is less frequent than in a decentralized organization, the centralization may encourage the implementation of innovations, once the innovation-decision is made.” (Page 379-380.)
Sounds like Reform and Opening.
Saturday, November 6, 2010
Hayek's Relevance in China vs. the West, 6th Nov., 2010.
The title of an article I found, 哈耶克的“自发社会秩序”理论与中国经济改革的思路选择 [Hayek's "Spontaneous Order" Theory and China's Economic Reform Ideas and Choices] by Sen Wei (韦森), looked promising. However, most of the article focused on the philosophical background, i.e. the Scottish moral philosophers, of Hayek’s work. The only concrete sentence about Hayek and the Chinese economy was:The achievement and glistening historical path of the Chinese economic reforms, especially the huge success of early-stage rural reforms, to an extent can be considered a confirmation and development of that which clearly came out of the logical background of Hayek’s spontaneous order.
The author received his Ph.D. from the University of Sydney, and is now a professor of economics at Fudan University. In 2009, he gave a speech at the Academic Seminar on Professor Zhenglai Deng’s (邓正来) New Book on Hayek’s Theories of Liberalism.
Nobody should think that Hayek’s influence in the West is very big. Currently, there are more people in China that know about Hayek than there are in the West. Also, a lot of students of Western academic circles say Hayek is hard to understand. I’ll give you an example: Hayek’s last book, The Fatal Conceit, was published in 1988. I went back to the University of Sydney in 2001 and borrowed the book. When I was reading it, I discovered the book had been there for two years, and only two people had borrowed the book. One of those people was myself. One time, the former president of the University of Chicago College of Law, Saul Levmore, visited Shanghai. He asked me what I was researching, I said “I’m studying Hayek.”
He said “Oh, studying Hayek! It’s very hard to understand him.”
It’s harder to discuss Hayek’s thoughts with foreign economic circles. Even Hayek, himself, recognized this. During his later years, at the Bartley lectures, he said, referring to economic studies, “I’m an outsider.”
It doesn’t matter if the majority of foreign academics accept and understand Hayek, or not, because without a doubt, Hayek is one of the 20th Century’s greatest thinkers. This point we certainly need to remember.
I borrowed The Fatal Conceit and Collectivist Economic Planning from the Armacost Library. The Fatal Conceit has been checked out four times in the last five years (including myself), and the last time Collectivist Economic Planning was checked out was in 1998.
John Stossel blogged on Thursday that he will confront the New York Times over it’s referencing of Hayek's writings as “long-dormant ideas,” in a class of “once-obscure texts by dead writers.”
He quotes David Boaz’ piece on Cato@Liberty,So that's, you know, "long-dormant ideas" like those of F. A. Hayek, the winner of the Nobel Prize in Economics, who met with President Reagan at the White House, whose book The Constitution of Liberty was declared by Margaret Thatcher "This is what we believe," who was described by Milton Friedman as "the most important social thinker of the 20th century" and by White House economic adviser Lawrence H. Summers as the author of "the single most important thing to learn from an economics course today," who is the hero of The Commanding Heights, the book and PBS series by Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw, and whose book The Road to Serfdom has never gone out of print and has sold 100,000 copies this year.
He didn’t mention his influence on China. I guess that’s why this is a good topic for my Latin Honors.
Friday, November 5, 2010
S. C. Tsiang and Taiwan, 5th Nov., 2010.
Today I read a rather long article on S. C. Tsiang (蒋硕杰). The article was written by Professor Chunsin Hwang (黄春兴), of the National Tsinghua University (Taiwan). I contacted him while I was doing this research in China, and he was very helpful. He learned the Austrian School of Economics from S. C. Tsiang while he was a graduate student at the National Tsinghua University. He later got a Ph.D. from the University of Rochester. He is now an associate professor of economics at the National Tsinghua University. Interested students can enroll in his course, ECON 6171 The Economic Theories of the Austrian School.
According to him, "Before economic reform and opening-up, Austrian ideas were the main topics attacked, distorted, and criticized by communists. After opening-up, most Chinese scholars who read [the Austrian School] emphasized its political philosophy, not economic analysis."
In 2008, he published an article with the 九鼎公共事务研究所 (Cathay Institute for Public Affairs), titled "奥地利学派对蒋硕杰经济思想的影响 [The Influence of the Austrian School on S.C. Tsiang’s Economic Ideas]."
The first paragraph makes an excellent point, which I translated as "During Taiwan's process of development during the last 60 years, it was first economic affairs that were liberalized step by step, then it expanded to political affairs. This verifies a long standing and common belief of traditional liberals: Only after economic liberty takes root can political liberty have a stable and continuous development. Therefore, any discussion about the Taiwanese opening up of political liberalization in the 1980s should not overlook the liberalization process of foreign exchange and interest rates that started in the 1950s. At that time, Mr. Tsiang explained economic liberty's most important people. He has become an extremely important topic for his contribution to the inheritance and evolution of liberal economic thought, as well as the understanding of Taiwan's process of liberalization."
The article then goes into S. C. Tsiang's opinions on Walras' Law, D. H. Robertson, time dimension, currency, boom and busts, and industrial policy. Even though 'Hayek' and 'Austrian Economics' do not appear in the index of 蒋硕杰先生悼念录 [The S. C. Tsiang Memorial Collection], Professor Hwang believes "S. C. Tsiang's discussions on the misapplication of Walras' Law, opposition to government created credit expansion, and persistence on currency theory adapting the use of analysis method are all based on the foundation of Austrian Time Dimension theory."
Unfortunately for the Chinese Austrian School, he didn't stay in China. According to his New York Times Obituary, he "[R]eturned to China briefly to teach and work in the Chinese Central Bank. When the Communists came to power in 1949, Professor Tsiang fled to the United States, where he joined the International Monetary Fund. [ . . . ] In the 1960's, he was a professor of economics at the University of Rochester. In 1969, he joined the faculty at Cornell and remained there until retiring in 1985. He was a pioneer in the theory of money flows and exchange-rate markets."
Thursday, November 4, 2010
The I, Pencil Institute and Weiying Zhang, 4th Nov., 2010
Weiying Zhang is solitary; today, those people that once were his comrades-in-arms have all turned into his opponents. When they all turned to Keynes, turned to "the market, overall, is good, but sometimes needs the government's guidance," kind of interventionism, Weiying Zhang was the only one to hold on to his faith in the market.